Thursday, April 11, 2013

Fwd: Why India's welfare plans are anti-poor by Laveesh Bhandari in Bus Standard



---------- Forwarded message ----------
From: sanjeev nayyar

Points made by Author 1. Food inflation is a result of increasing fiscal deficit, rising farm wages and transmission of global food inflation.     2. Fertilizer subsides reach beneficiaries in an inadequate manner, encourage under and over use of fertilizer that impacts productivity. CACP has also tied in the impact on the Fisc.     3. Energy subsidy pushed up fiscal deficit, thus push up food prices thus anti-poor.     4. Subsidy on power encourages overdrawing of surface power, incorrect productions patterns for e.g. water-rich comonodies are grown in low-water access areas.     5. By holding excess buffer stocks of food grain impacts fisc since it is inefficient expenditure.     6. Reforms created high growth and thus enabled welfare.

Welfare without growth and subsidies without economic efficiency work against the poor. Money should be used to create Assets which in turn enhance demand, efficiency and income like NDA's National Highway Project.

Why India's welfare plans are anti-poor by Laveesh Bhandari 11/4/13

A CACP study shows how the Fisc, rising farm wages and international forces are stoking inflation

It's good to see that independent thought is still present in the government. When one part of the government comes out with a serious and objective piece on how the government itself has been responsible for creating food inflation, hopefully the government is more likely to take note.

The Commission for Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP) has come out with a discussion paper (the fourth in a series) titled "Taming Food Inflation in India", penned by its Chairman Ashok Gulati and independent researcher Shweta Saini. Using econometric analyses, the paper shows how food inflation is an outcome of an increasing fiscal deficit, rising farm wages and transmission of global food inflation. These three items together account for 98 per cent of the variations in India's food inflation between 1995-96 and December 2012. In other words, economic growth or population growth are not responsible for inflation. They, no doubt, provide the environment where external and internal forces created by government action are pushing up prices in an inordinately sustained manner.

Unlike most other pieces of wisdom originating from the government, CACP quite unambiguously points to the fiscal deficit as among the chief culprits. And, more importantly, mentions a small checklist of critical reforms that can arrest deficit, while maintaining or improving agriculture productivity, and simultaneously giving a boost to overall economic growth. For all these reasons, CACP's discussion paper deserves greater attention than the various reports we are accustomed to seeing - or even the Plan document for that matter.

Fertiliser subsidies are among the worst directed subsidies, not only do they reach the beneficiaries in an inadequate manner, the way they are given out simultaneously encourage underuse and overuse of the fertiliser that itself impacts productivity. This is all well known, but that CACP has also tied in the impact on the Fisc. The suggestion of directly targeting subsidies based on farm size is good, and one of those ideas whose time has come, especially with rapidly expanding banking networks and beneficiary identification mechanisms.

Energy subsidies are another item that CACP alludes to. The argument is that energy subsidies push up the fiscal deficit and, therefore, push up food prices. This, in turn, impacts poor Indian households quite adversely. The argument, therefore, that subsidies help the poor is quite flawed - something that CACP does well to underscore. But there is another problem with subsidies, such as those for power. They encourage overdrawing of sub-surface power, inappropriate production patterns are undesirable outcome - water-rich commodities are grown in low-water access areas, for instance. Thus, both resource allocation and production patterns are not optimal. The fact that subsidies adversely impact prices is critically important for policy makers and stakeholders to understand if India has to survive.

It is well known that India does not need to keep such a high buffer stock of food grains. It is not clear why the government insists on it, and it is refreshing to see CACP also point out this anomaly. So much buffer stock, of course, impacts the Fisc since it is inefficient expenditure. Also, it impacts agriculture production patterns adversely. For, if the government continues to purchase and hold food grains, the incentive to shift to high-value foods, such as proteins and fruits and vegetables, is reduced.

The study then also implicates the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (MGNREGA) as another possible source of inflation. However, the analysis here is a bit weaker and it requires greater rigour. Notwithstanding these, the point is clear, that the priority needs to be such that a welfare programme not only provides welfare, but also boosts productivity and production. Given that the first stage of MGNREGA is over and it has matured as a welfare programme, expanding its scope of operations such that production and productivity improve should be rapidly implemented.

International forces are another source of inflation, and many believe that India can do little on that. Not entirely true. India is among the largest consumers of food items and also among the largest growers. What India does has a significant impact on international prices. CACP may not say it, but it is high time India built a mechanism for both impacting international prices to its advantage and insuring the domestic consumer against fluctuations owing to international influences.

But the larger point of the CACP study needs to be considered. Few departments of the government are coming out with visionary agendas any more. It appears as if large parts of the government have given up. The Planning Commission and the latest documents it has brought out look like tired rehashes of the past. The Economic Survey has become just a collection of sentences put together by a command and control economic advisory set-up. A chapter or two put in by well-meaning individuals are neither here nor there. Statements by policy makers are more about the past than about the future.

India needs to look ahead. The reforms created high growth that enabled welfare. But welfare without growth and subsidies without economic efficiency work against the poor. Food inflation is one such symptom. Low job creation is another. As India enters a high deficit, low-growth phase, it needs to look ahead - for the sake of its poor and underprivileged if for no one else. Looking ahead requires us to clean up where we are going wrong - a large, sustained and growing fiscal deficit is the first effect of poor economic management. Sustained inflation is another. Slowing growth is a third. A worsening current account deficit is yet another. India is entering a downward spiral and the only way out is to look ahead and incorporate sensible reforms.
 
Warm Regards
sanjeev nayyar
www.suryaconsulting.net
Unlocking Value from Knowledge through Innovation and Sharing
Contacts 91 98211 12693, sanjeev@suryaconsulting.net, sanjeevnayyar108@gmail.com
Skype Name - sanjeevnayyarmumbai2001
https://twitter.com/sanjeev1927
To unsubscribe write back



--
sent from samsung galaxy note, so please excuse brevity

No comments: